Dynamic optimal execution in a mixed-market-impact Hawkes price model (Q261925): Difference between revisions

From MaRDI portal
Importer (talk | contribs)
Created a new Item
 
Importer (talk | contribs)
Changed an Item
Property / review text
 
This paper concerns a financial model with ``mesoscopic'' time scale (intermediate between high and low frequencies), the authors considering it more convenient since the order flow is essentially discrete. The price model is defined via a fundamental price component \(S\) and a ``mesoscopic'' price deviation \(D\): for any \(t\in[0,T)\), \(P_t= S_t+ D_t\). Denoting by \(X\) the strategy, \(dS_t= q(\nu dN_t+\varepsilon dX_t)\), \(dD_t= -\rho D_t dt+{1\over q}[(1-\nu)dN_t+ (1-\varepsilon)dX_t]\), \(q> 0\), \(\nu\) being the market resilience parameter, \((N_t)\) is the process of market orders defined on a probability space \((\Omega,{\mathcal F},{\mathcal P})\), squares integrable (for any \(t\), \(\sup_{0\leq s\leq t}E(X^2_s),\,<\infty\)), with bounded variation. More specifically, \((N_t)\) is the impact Hawkes price model, meaning that \(N= N^+-N^-\), \(N^\pm\) admit the intensities \(\kappa^\pm\), and the Poisson measures \(n^\pm(dt, dv)\). The price process is impacted by the strategy \(X\), an \({\mathcal F}^{{\mathcal N}}\)-adapted, bounded variation right continuous left limited process, admissible if moreover \(X_0= x_0\), \(X_{T^+}= 0\) almost surely. This strategy induces a cost \(C(X)\). The aim is to find an explicit strategy which minimizes the expected cost \(E[C(X)]\). A ``price manipulation strategy'' is an admissible strategy such that \(E[C(X)]< 0\). The main results firstly provide an explicit optimal strategy and the associated value. Secondly, they determine necessary and sufficient conditions on the model parameters to exclude price manipulation strategies. Finally, in the case of the Poisson model (which cannot avoid price manipulation strategies), there exist simple and robust arbitrage strategies under the hypotheses \(\kappa^+= \kappa^->0\), \(N^+\) and \(N^-\) have the same jump law.
Property / review text: This paper concerns a financial model with ``mesoscopic'' time scale (intermediate between high and low frequencies), the authors considering it more convenient since the order flow is essentially discrete. The price model is defined via a fundamental price component \(S\) and a ``mesoscopic'' price deviation \(D\): for any \(t\in[0,T)\), \(P_t= S_t+ D_t\). Denoting by \(X\) the strategy, \(dS_t= q(\nu dN_t+\varepsilon dX_t)\), \(dD_t= -\rho D_t dt+{1\over q}[(1-\nu)dN_t+ (1-\varepsilon)dX_t]\), \(q> 0\), \(\nu\) being the market resilience parameter, \((N_t)\) is the process of market orders defined on a probability space \((\Omega,{\mathcal F},{\mathcal P})\), squares integrable (for any \(t\), \(\sup_{0\leq s\leq t}E(X^2_s),\,<\infty\)), with bounded variation. More specifically, \((N_t)\) is the impact Hawkes price model, meaning that \(N= N^+-N^-\), \(N^\pm\) admit the intensities \(\kappa^\pm\), and the Poisson measures \(n^\pm(dt, dv)\). The price process is impacted by the strategy \(X\), an \({\mathcal F}^{{\mathcal N}}\)-adapted, bounded variation right continuous left limited process, admissible if moreover \(X_0= x_0\), \(X_{T^+}= 0\) almost surely. This strategy induces a cost \(C(X)\). The aim is to find an explicit strategy which minimizes the expected cost \(E[C(X)]\). A ``price manipulation strategy'' is an admissible strategy such that \(E[C(X)]< 0\). The main results firstly provide an explicit optimal strategy and the associated value. Secondly, they determine necessary and sufficient conditions on the model parameters to exclude price manipulation strategies. Finally, in the case of the Poisson model (which cannot avoid price manipulation strategies), there exist simple and robust arbitrage strategies under the hypotheses \(\kappa^+= \kappa^->0\), \(N^+\) and \(N^-\) have the same jump law. / rank
 
Normal rank
Property / reviewed by
 
Property / reviewed by: Monique Pontier / rank
 
Normal rank
Property / Mathematics Subject Classification ID
 
Property / Mathematics Subject Classification ID: 91G10 / rank
 
Normal rank
Property / Mathematics Subject Classification ID
 
Property / Mathematics Subject Classification ID: 91B24 / rank
 
Normal rank
Property / Mathematics Subject Classification ID
 
Property / Mathematics Subject Classification ID: 60G55 / rank
 
Normal rank
Property / Mathematics Subject Classification ID
 
Property / Mathematics Subject Classification ID: 49J15 / rank
 
Normal rank
Property / zbMATH DE Number
 
Property / zbMATH DE Number: 6560421 / rank
 
Normal rank
Property / zbMATH Keywords
 
market impact model
Property / zbMATH Keywords: market impact model / rank
 
Normal rank
Property / zbMATH Keywords
 
optimal execution
Property / zbMATH Keywords: optimal execution / rank
 
Normal rank
Property / zbMATH Keywords
 
Hawkes processes
Property / zbMATH Keywords: Hawkes processes / rank
 
Normal rank
Property / zbMATH Keywords
 
market microstructure
Property / zbMATH Keywords: market microstructure / rank
 
Normal rank
Property / zbMATH Keywords
 
high-frequency trading
Property / zbMATH Keywords: high-frequency trading / rank
 
Normal rank
Property / zbMATH Keywords
 
price manipulations
Property / zbMATH Keywords: price manipulations / rank
 
Normal rank

Revision as of 13:36, 27 June 2023

scientific article
Language Label Description Also known as
English
Dynamic optimal execution in a mixed-market-impact Hawkes price model
scientific article

    Statements

    Dynamic optimal execution in a mixed-market-impact Hawkes price model (English)
    0 references
    0 references
    0 references
    29 March 2016
    0 references
    This paper concerns a financial model with ``mesoscopic'' time scale (intermediate between high and low frequencies), the authors considering it more convenient since the order flow is essentially discrete. The price model is defined via a fundamental price component \(S\) and a ``mesoscopic'' price deviation \(D\): for any \(t\in[0,T)\), \(P_t= S_t+ D_t\). Denoting by \(X\) the strategy, \(dS_t= q(\nu dN_t+\varepsilon dX_t)\), \(dD_t= -\rho D_t dt+{1\over q}[(1-\nu)dN_t+ (1-\varepsilon)dX_t]\), \(q> 0\), \(\nu\) being the market resilience parameter, \((N_t)\) is the process of market orders defined on a probability space \((\Omega,{\mathcal F},{\mathcal P})\), squares integrable (for any \(t\), \(\sup_{0\leq s\leq t}E(X^2_s),\,<\infty\)), with bounded variation. More specifically, \((N_t)\) is the impact Hawkes price model, meaning that \(N= N^+-N^-\), \(N^\pm\) admit the intensities \(\kappa^\pm\), and the Poisson measures \(n^\pm(dt, dv)\). The price process is impacted by the strategy \(X\), an \({\mathcal F}^{{\mathcal N}}\)-adapted, bounded variation right continuous left limited process, admissible if moreover \(X_0= x_0\), \(X_{T^+}= 0\) almost surely. This strategy induces a cost \(C(X)\). The aim is to find an explicit strategy which minimizes the expected cost \(E[C(X)]\). A ``price manipulation strategy'' is an admissible strategy such that \(E[C(X)]< 0\). The main results firstly provide an explicit optimal strategy and the associated value. Secondly, they determine necessary and sufficient conditions on the model parameters to exclude price manipulation strategies. Finally, in the case of the Poisson model (which cannot avoid price manipulation strategies), there exist simple and robust arbitrage strategies under the hypotheses \(\kappa^+= \kappa^->0\), \(N^+\) and \(N^-\) have the same jump law.
    0 references
    market impact model
    0 references
    optimal execution
    0 references
    Hawkes processes
    0 references
    market microstructure
    0 references
    high-frequency trading
    0 references
    price manipulations
    0 references

    Identifiers

    0 references
    0 references
    0 references
    0 references
    0 references